skip to main | skip to sidebar
Global Labour Column Archive
  • HOME
    • ABOUT US
    • GLC ANTHOLOGIES
  • LINKS
    • RECOMMENDED SITES
    • DISCLAIMER
  • AUTHORS
  • GLOBAL BOARD
  • CONTACT
  • GLU
  • ICDD
  • Follow Us on Twitter
  • Tuesday, October 17, 2017

    A perspective on wage inequality from the ILO Global Wage Report

    Patrick Belser
    In recent years the share of labour compensation in Gross Domestic Product (GDP) declined in many countries around the world. At the same time wage inequality reached levels considered by many to be both socially and economically unsustainable. Too much inequality not only erodes social cohesion, it also reduces opportunities for social mobility, hurts consumption by lower income groups, weakens the middle class, and creates societies in which elites live in a separate world. 

    Reducing inequality has thus become more central for policy makers in many parts of the world, as is reflected not only in the International Labour Organisation (ILO) decent work agenda, but also in the 2030 Sustainable Development Agenda, which calls for decent work for all as well as fiscal, wage and social protection policies to progressively achieve greater equality.
    The latest ILO Global Wage Report focuses on wage inequality, taking as the starting point that overall wage inequality results from a combination of differences in average wages between enterprises and wage inequality within enterprises.
    This enterprise perspective differs from the more traditional focus on skills as the major source of inequality. Many studies have documented how technology, globalisation, pressures from financial markets, labour market deregulation and trade unions’ weaker bargaining power have contributed to increased wage inequality between highly skilled workers and workers with lower levels of education. But individual characteristics alone (including age, educational attainment, and years of tenure) do a relatively poor job of explaining the variation in workers’ wages. The simple human capital model used in the Global Wage Report shows that there are sometimes enormous differences between people's actual wages and the wages predicted for these individual characteristics. The discrepancy is large anywhere in the distribution, but particularly large at the top, where workers are hugely ‘overpaid’ for their characteristics, and at the bottom, where they are grossly ‘underpaid’.


    Inequality between enterprises matters

    Recent literature has emphasised the importance of differences in average wages between enterprises as a source of wage inequality. Research at the OECD, for example, found that the most productive firms are pulling ahead, and this productivity gap is causing a wage gap: ‘When higher productivity means higher wages, the increasing productivity gaps between firms could translate into wage gaps. Indeed, that’s exactly what we see in the data’, write Berlingieri, Blanchenay, and Crisculolo (2017).

    The ILO Global Wage Report shows that in many countries there is indeed some correspondence between a low level of wage inequality among individuals and a low level of wage inequality between enterprises (as in Norway, which has low wage inequality and where 90% of enterprises have middle-of-the-road average wages), or between higher levels of inequality of each type (as in the United Kingdom, which has more wage inequality and a higher proportion of enterprises with very low or very high average wages). Developing countries have both higher wage inequality and more inequality between enterprises than developed countries.

    Don’t overlook wage inequality within enterprises

    But inequality between firms is only part of the story. Using the European Structure of Earnings Survey, the Global Wage Report finds that on average in Europe, wage inequality within enterprises accounts for a considerable 42% of the total variance in wages, with notable country variations (see Figure 1).
    Figure 1: Decomposition of wage inequality between and within enterprises in Europe 

    In the USA, a recent study (Song et al, 2015) shows that wage inequality within enterprises accounts for more than half of total wage inequality. In other words, if there was no wage inequality within enterprises - if all workers were to receive exactly their enterprise’s average wage - wage inequality in the USA would be cut by more than half. 

    Of course, reducing wage inequality to zero within enterprises is neither realistic nor desirable. Some employees have more responsibilities and skills than others, and these should be adequately rewarded. But has inequality within some enterprises gone too far?
    When comparing the wages of individuals to the average wage of the enterprises in which they work, the Wage Report finds that in medium and large European enterprises, most people (close to 80%) are paid less than the average wage of the enterprise in which they work. In real estate and financial services, 99% of workers earn less than the average. The average is thus a very imperfect measure of what workers in those enterprises really earn.

    Zooming in on the enterprises with top average wages, we find that inequalities grow to sometimes enormous levels. This can be seen in Figure 2, which ranks all enterprises according to their average wages, and also shows the highest and the lowest wage in these groups of enterprises. In the top enterprises, wage inequality explodes.

    Figure 2: average wages and wage inequality in Europe (22 countries)
    Source: ILO Global Wage Report (ILO estimates based on the weighted average using 22 economies from the Eurostat SES). The countries are Belgium, Bulgaria, Cyprus, Czech Republic, Estonia, Finland, France, Greece, Hungary, Italy, Latvia, Lithuania, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Romania, Slovakia, Spain, Sweden and the United Kingdom.

    Strikingly, what is true for overall wage inequality is also true for the gender pay gap. While the hourly gender pay gap for Europe is about 20%, in the 1% of enterprises with the highest average wages in Europe, the gap amounts to no less than 48%.

    What can be done to reduce wage inequality?

    Beyond improving skills and education for those at the bottom of the pyramid, what can be done to reduce wage inequality?
    Given the magnitude of wage inequality within enterprises documented here, it is clear that enterprises’ self-regulation has a role to play in keeping wage inequality within socially acceptable bounds. Many CEOs effectively determine their own pay, and shareholders have often been unable to ensure executive remuneration in line with social values or even company performance. Initiatives to regulate top wages have focused on the transparency of remuneration and on shareholders’ say over pay. Now there are questions as to whether more regulation or higher taxes are necessary to discourage compensation packages based on short-term shareholder value rather than long-term enterprise performance.

    Minimum wage legislation and collective bargaining also have a central role to play to reduce inequality between and within enterprises, as the experience of various European countries and Alvarez et al.’s case study of Brazil (2016) have shown. But differences in the way collective bargaining is organised have different effects. When collective bargaining is at the company or workplace level, the effect is restricted to wage inequality within enterprises. When collective bargaining takes place at the national, industry or branch level in multi-employer settings with coordination across levels, a larger proportion of workers are covered and inequality is likely to be reduced both within and between enterprises. The extension of collective agreements by governments to all workers in a particular sector or country can reinforce these effects.

    Given that differences in average wages between enterprises are an important determinant of overall wage inequality, promoting broad-based productivity growth among enterprises may simultaneously permit higher average wages and reduce wage inequality. OECD research suggests that ‘laggard firms’ can be encouraged to imitate the productivity performance of ‘frontier firms’ through adoption of new technologies and best practices. According to Criscuolo (2015), ‘some firms “get it” and others don’t’.

    Things may not, alas, be so simple. One major policy challenge comes from fragmentation, or what David Weil (2014: 4) calls ‘fissured workplaces’: the transformation in how business organises work, focusing on core activities and shifting many low paid jobs – janitors, security guards, drivers, front-desk staff and so on - to separate employers. In such cases, there may be little scope for improving productivity in the low value added segment. As Weil points out,

    ...the new organization of the workplace also undermines the mechanisms that once led to the workforce sharing part of the value created by large corporate employers. By shedding employment to other parties, lead companies change a wage-setting problem into a contracting decision. The result is stagnation of real wages for many of the jobs formerly done inside (Weil, 2014: 4). 
    The solution may thus have to include responsible purchasing practices by lead companies as well as initiatives to ensure the inclusion of all parts of the supply chain into collective bargaining agreements. 


    Download this article as pdf

    Patrick Belser is a senior economist in the ILO and co-author of the Global Wage Report.

    References
    Alvarez, J.; Engbom, N.; Benguria, F.; and Moser, C. (2017) Firms and the Decline in Earnings Inequality in Brazil, Columbia Business School Research Paper No 17-47.

    Berlingieri, G.; Blanchenay, P.; and Crisculolo, C. (2017) ‘A study of 16 countries shows that the most productive firms (and their employees) are pulling away from everyone else’, Harvard Business Review, August 24.

    Criscuolo, C. (2015) ‘Productivity is soaring at top firms and sluggish everywhere else’, Harvard Business Review, August 24.

    ILO (2017) Global wage report 2016/17: Wage Inequality in the Workplace, ILO, Geneva.

    Song, J.; Price, D.; Guvenen, F.; Bloom, N.; and von Wachter, T. (2015) Firming up inequality, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 21199, Cambridge (USA).

    Weil, D. (2014) The Fissured Workplace: why work became so bad for so many and what can be done to improve it, Harvard University Press, Cambridge USA.

    Posted in: ILO,Inequality,Wage Inequality
    Email This BlogThis! Share to X Share to Facebook
    Newer Post Older Post Home

    0 Comments:

    Post a Comment

    Share

    Twitter Facebook Stumbleupon Favorites More

    Subscribe to the Mailing List

    If you want to subscribe to the GLC mailing list, please click here or send an empty email to "List-GLColumn-subscribe@global-labour-university.org"

    Contribute to the GLC

    If you want to contribute to the Global Labour Column, please read here the Guidelines for Contributions

    Languages






    Donations

    More Info

    Popular Posts

      T-Shirt Economics: Labour in the Imperialist World Economy
      Chinese Construction Companies in Africa: A Challenge for Trade Unions
      Ruskin, the trade union college, is under siege

    TAGS

    Trade Unions Financial Crisis Workers' rights Globalisation Neoliberalism Labour Market Collective Bargaining Decent Work Inequality Labour Standards Wage Social Movements Europe Development Strategies Struggle Progressive alliances Strike Growth Labour Labour rights Financial Market Tax Financial Regulation Social Security Public Investment Social Democracy South Africa Economic Democracy Fiscal Space Germany Informal Economy Corporate Governance Freedom of Association ILO Minimum Wage United States Competitiveness Human Rights Labour Movements Trade Union Austerity Central Bank Environment Free Trade Free Trade Agreement Greece Labour Movement Social Protection State Funding Transnational Solidarity Unemployment Vietnam Workers’ Rights Crowd Work Domestic Workers Economic Crisis Education Employment Forced Labour France Global Warming Labour Market Flexibility Labour Statistics Migration National Minimum Wage Public Works Programmes Trade Union Divisions Workers' unity Agriculture Brexit Care Work Construction Sector Cooperatives Crisis Economic Alternatives Economic Reform Farmworkers Financialisation Globalization Indonesia Just Transition Labour Process Liberalisation Macroeconomic Policy NUM Nationalism Occupational Health Organising Outsourcing Portugal Privatisation Refugees Regulation Reserve Army of Labour Right to strike Social Dialogue Social Justice Solidarity Tax Evasion Welfare State Workers Rights Workers’ Organisations AMCU Africa Alternative Sources of Power Anti-privatisation Anti-union Violence Automobiles Brazil Business and Human Rights Capital Flight Capitalism Chinese Investment Climate Change Collectivity Colombia Community Monitoring Conference Corporate Transparency Coup Cuba Debt Restructuring Decriminalisation Demand Democracy Developed and Developing Countries Development Digitisation Disciplining of the superfluous labour force Domestic Work Economic Development Egypt Elections Entrepreneurship Eurozone Crisis Executive Compensation Factory Occupations Fair Trade Farm Workers Feminism Finance Financial Crises Financial Innovation Financial crisis. Fiscal Austerity Food Sovereignty G20 Gender Gentrification Global Health Global Multiplier Great Depression Great Recession Hawkers Health Hotel Housekeepers Human Rights due Diligence India Industrial Relations Informal Employment Institutions International Aid Policy International Framework Agreements Investment Partnership (TTIP) Investment Partnerships Iran Korean Shipbuilding Industry Kuznets Labor Labour Broking Labour Income Share Labour Markets Labour Reform Leadership Left Legislation Loi Travail Macroeconomic Performance Management Manufacturing Marshall Plan Metal Workers Migrant Domestic Workers Militarised Capitalism Mineworkers NASVI National Health Service Neolibaralism Networking New Progressive Consensus Online Campaigning Options for the Euro Area Paternalism Patriarchy Pensions Performance Standards Political Alliances Poverty Reduction Precariousness Prison Labour Prisoners Private Plantations Progressive Tax Reform Protectionism Protests Public Policy Quebec Racism Rank-and-File Member Redistribution Regulation of Labour Rent Seeking Rural Development Ruskin SEWA Securitization Sex Work Shadow Banking Shaft Stewards Social Audit Social Development Social Movement Social Transformation Solidarity Economy Spain Sportswear Industry State Stellenbosch Street Trading Street Vendors Strike Ban Strikes Structural Changes Supply Chains Swedish Model Tertiary Education Top Income Shares Tourism Trade Liberalisation Trade Misinvoicing Transatlantic Trade Transformation Transparency Transport Trump Tunsia Turkey Unfree Labour Union 4.0 Union Strategy Unions Universal Health Coverage (UHC) Voluntary Initiatives Wage Employment Wage Inequality Wage Share West Africa Wild Cat Strike Winelands Women Women’s Movement Workers` Organization Youth

    PUBLICATIONS

    Click here to view more

    Blog Archive

    • ►  2020 (1)
      • ►  September (1)
    • ▼  2017 (40)
      • ►  December (4)
      • ►  November (2)
      • ▼  October (3)
        • Can the future of work be uncoupled from productiv...
        • A perspective on wage inequality from the ILO Glob...
        • Why always wildcat strikes in Vietnam?
      • ►  September (5)
      • ►  July (4)
      • ►  June (6)
      • ►  May (4)
      • ►  April (3)
      • ►  March (2)
      • ►  February (4)
      • ►  January (3)
    • ►  2016 (34)
      • ►  December (3)
      • ►  November (2)
      • ►  October (2)
      • ►  September (4)
      • ►  August (4)
      • ►  July (2)
      • ►  June (3)
      • ►  May (4)
      • ►  April (1)
      • ►  March (4)
      • ►  February (3)
      • ►  January (2)
    • ►  2015 (32)
      • ►  December (2)
      • ►  November (5)
      • ►  October (4)
      • ►  September (2)
      • ►  August (1)
      • ►  July (2)
      • ►  June (5)
      • ►  May (3)
      • ►  April (2)
      • ►  March (2)
      • ►  February (3)
      • ►  January (1)
    • ►  2014 (32)
      • ►  December (3)
      • ►  November (1)
      • ►  October (4)
      • ►  September (3)
      • ►  August (1)
      • ►  July (3)
      • ►  June (6)
      • ►  May (2)
      • ►  April (3)
      • ►  March (2)
      • ►  February (2)
      • ►  January (2)
    • ►  2013 (41)
      • ►  December (3)
      • ►  November (2)
      • ►  October (5)
      • ►  September (4)
      • ►  August (1)
      • ►  July (4)
      • ►  June (3)
      • ►  May (4)
      • ►  April (3)
      • ►  March (4)
      • ►  February (4)
      • ►  January (4)
    • ►  2012 (35)
      • ►  December (3)
      • ►  November (4)
      • ►  October (4)
      • ►  September (2)
      • ►  August (2)
      • ►  July (2)
      • ►  June (2)
      • ►  May (4)
      • ►  April (3)
      • ►  March (3)
      • ►  February (4)
      • ►  January (2)
    • ►  2011 (39)
      • ►  December (3)
      • ►  November (4)
      • ►  October (3)
      • ►  September (4)
      • ►  August (3)
      • ►  July (2)
      • ►  June (3)
      • ►  May (3)
      • ►  April (4)
      • ►  March (4)
      • ►  February (4)
      • ►  January (2)
    • ►  2010 (39)
      • ►  December (3)
      • ►  November (5)
      • ►  October (4)
      • ►  September (2)
      • ►  August (2)
      • ►  July (3)
      • ►  June (4)
      • ►  May (1)
      • ►  April (4)
      • ►  March (4)
      • ►  February (4)
      • ►  January (3)
    • ►  2009 (5)
      • ►  December (3)
      • ►  November (2)

     
    Copyright © 2011 Global Labour Column Archive | Powered by Blogger
    Design by Free WordPress Themes | Bloggerized by Lasantha - Premium Blogger Themes | 100 WP Themes